Jeanne Stansak
dylan_black_2025
Jeanne Stansak
dylan_black_2025
A monopoly is a market structure in which an individual firm has sufficient control of an industry or market. They determine the terms of access to other firms.
A natural monopoly occurs when an individual firm comes to dominate an industry by producing goods and services at the lowest possible production cost. Since other firms cannot compete with these low costs, it drives them out of the business and allows the dominant firm to monopolize the industry. Natural monopolies are actually beneficial to society because they charge low prices and promote productive efficiency.
In a monopoly graph, the demand curve is located above the marginal revenue cost curve. This is because they have to lower their price in order to sell each additional unit. This is known as the inability to price discriminate. Because demand is decreasing, a consumer's willingness to buy at a higher Q is lower, meaning the additional revenue you'll receive from each unit decreases.
For a monopoly, the marginal revenue curve is lower on the graph than the demand curve, because the change in price required to get the next sale applies not just to that next sale but to all the sales before it. For example, if you can sell 5 units for 8 each, you have to sell each of those first 5 for 10, meaning your marginal revenue is always less than demand.
This is kind of a tricky fact to wrap around your head, but in essence, MR < D because a monopoly cannot price-discriminate. Its additional revenue is always less than what you're willing to pay at that quantity because it's selling a higher quantity. If the firm could charge your exact willingness, MR would equal D.
Their profit-maximizing profit output is where MR=MC. The price is determined by going from where MR=MC, up to the demand curve.
Many times, when drawing a monopoly graph, we are asked to show either a profit or a loss. We use the cost curve, ATC, to show it. When we are showing a profit, the ATC will be located below the price on the monopoly graph. We shade the area that represents the profit.
Calculating a Monopoly's Profit
In this particular graph, the firm is earning a total revenue of 2 x 200 = 1200 - 800).
You can also use the area of a rectangle formula to calculate profit!
In this particular graph, the firm is earning a total revenue of 9 x 100 = 500-400).
You can also use the area of a rectangle formula to calculate loss!
Note that a monopoly underproduces in a market. The socially-optimal quantity and price for this market would be the point where D = MC. Instead, a monopoly deliberately underproduces and overcharges, causing deadweight loss.
Profit-maximizing price and output (sometimes referred to as loss-minimizing): The output is determined where MR = MC, and then we go up to the demand curve and over to identify the price. (On the graph below it is Q1 and P4.) This is the point we identified earlier
Socially optimal price and output: This is located where P = MC. This is also referred to as the allocatively efficient point on a monopoly graph. This point requires regulation from the government in order to produce here. This is usually done via a price ceiling, which keeps prices low. This forces the monopoly to produce a more allocatively efficient output and eliminate deadweight loss (DWL). (On the graph below it is Q3 and P2.). However, this could also lead to losses if ATC is higher at the socially optimal point.
Pros | Cons |
Increases output | Firm is still productively inefficient (P != min ATC) |
Decreases price level | Can drive the firm to experience losses |
Forces the firm to produce the allocative efficient level of output |
Fair-return price and output: This is where P = ATC. This should not be confused with the productively efficient point of P = minimum ATC. This is the point on a monopoly graph where total revenue (TR) = total cost (TC), meaning that the monopoly makes a normal profit. This is usually accomplished via a price ceiling. (On the graph below it is Q4 and P1.). At this point, profits are normal, but there may still be a small amount of deadweight loss. This is oftentimes a compromise between the profit-maximizing point and the socially-optimal point.
Price and output that maximizes total revenue (TR): This is located where MR=0. This point is also used to identify the elastic and inelastic parts of the demand curve. (On the graph below it is Q2 and P3.)
Pros | Cons |
Increases Ouput | Firms can be over-allocating resources |
Decreases Price Level | Firms may be overproducing |
Can force the firm to become more productively efficient | May require a government subsidy to enforce |
In the elastic region, a monopoly can lower the price and still increase their total revenue (TR). However, in the inelastic region, if they lower their price, they decrease their total revenue (remember the Total Revenue Test!). A monopoly will never willingly produce in the inelastic region because it would lower their profits (marginal revenue is negative, while marginal costs continue to increase. In order for them to produce in the inelastic region, the government has to regulate them with a price ceiling or provide support through a subsidy. (See the graph of both a monopoly and a corresponding TR curve below).
<< Hide Menu
Jeanne Stansak
dylan_black_2025
Jeanne Stansak
dylan_black_2025
A monopoly is a market structure in which an individual firm has sufficient control of an industry or market. They determine the terms of access to other firms.
A natural monopoly occurs when an individual firm comes to dominate an industry by producing goods and services at the lowest possible production cost. Since other firms cannot compete with these low costs, it drives them out of the business and allows the dominant firm to monopolize the industry. Natural monopolies are actually beneficial to society because they charge low prices and promote productive efficiency.
In a monopoly graph, the demand curve is located above the marginal revenue cost curve. This is because they have to lower their price in order to sell each additional unit. This is known as the inability to price discriminate. Because demand is decreasing, a consumer's willingness to buy at a higher Q is lower, meaning the additional revenue you'll receive from each unit decreases.
For a monopoly, the marginal revenue curve is lower on the graph than the demand curve, because the change in price required to get the next sale applies not just to that next sale but to all the sales before it. For example, if you can sell 5 units for 8 each, you have to sell each of those first 5 for 10, meaning your marginal revenue is always less than demand.
This is kind of a tricky fact to wrap around your head, but in essence, MR < D because a monopoly cannot price-discriminate. Its additional revenue is always less than what you're willing to pay at that quantity because it's selling a higher quantity. If the firm could charge your exact willingness, MR would equal D.
Their profit-maximizing profit output is where MR=MC. The price is determined by going from where MR=MC, up to the demand curve.
Many times, when drawing a monopoly graph, we are asked to show either a profit or a loss. We use the cost curve, ATC, to show it. When we are showing a profit, the ATC will be located below the price on the monopoly graph. We shade the area that represents the profit.
Calculating a Monopoly's Profit
In this particular graph, the firm is earning a total revenue of 2 x 200 = 1200 - 800).
You can also use the area of a rectangle formula to calculate profit!
In this particular graph, the firm is earning a total revenue of 9 x 100 = 500-400).
You can also use the area of a rectangle formula to calculate loss!
Note that a monopoly underproduces in a market. The socially-optimal quantity and price for this market would be the point where D = MC. Instead, a monopoly deliberately underproduces and overcharges, causing deadweight loss.
Profit-maximizing price and output (sometimes referred to as loss-minimizing): The output is determined where MR = MC, and then we go up to the demand curve and over to identify the price. (On the graph below it is Q1 and P4.) This is the point we identified earlier
Socially optimal price and output: This is located where P = MC. This is also referred to as the allocatively efficient point on a monopoly graph. This point requires regulation from the government in order to produce here. This is usually done via a price ceiling, which keeps prices low. This forces the monopoly to produce a more allocatively efficient output and eliminate deadweight loss (DWL). (On the graph below it is Q3 and P2.). However, this could also lead to losses if ATC is higher at the socially optimal point.
Pros | Cons |
Increases output | Firm is still productively inefficient (P != min ATC) |
Decreases price level | Can drive the firm to experience losses |
Forces the firm to produce the allocative efficient level of output |
Fair-return price and output: This is where P = ATC. This should not be confused with the productively efficient point of P = minimum ATC. This is the point on a monopoly graph where total revenue (TR) = total cost (TC), meaning that the monopoly makes a normal profit. This is usually accomplished via a price ceiling. (On the graph below it is Q4 and P1.). At this point, profits are normal, but there may still be a small amount of deadweight loss. This is oftentimes a compromise between the profit-maximizing point and the socially-optimal point.
Price and output that maximizes total revenue (TR): This is located where MR=0. This point is also used to identify the elastic and inelastic parts of the demand curve. (On the graph below it is Q2 and P3.)
Pros | Cons |
Increases Ouput | Firms can be over-allocating resources |
Decreases Price Level | Firms may be overproducing |
Can force the firm to become more productively efficient | May require a government subsidy to enforce |
In the elastic region, a monopoly can lower the price and still increase their total revenue (TR). However, in the inelastic region, if they lower their price, they decrease their total revenue (remember the Total Revenue Test!). A monopoly will never willingly produce in the inelastic region because it would lower their profits (marginal revenue is negative, while marginal costs continue to increase. In order for them to produce in the inelastic region, the government has to regulate them with a price ceiling or provide support through a subsidy. (See the graph of both a monopoly and a corresponding TR curve below).
© 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.