Browse By Unit
5 min readβ’june 18, 2024
Jeanne Stansak
dylan_black_2025
Jeanne Stansak
dylan_black_2025
Monopolistic competition is an imperfect market structure where many, various sized firms compete for market demand shares. This type of market structure has some characteristics that are the same or similar to perfect competition, as well as some characteristics that are the same or similar to monopolies. Some examples of monopolistic competition include fast-food restaurants, clothing companies, jewelers, hair salons, and furniture stores.
Many, various sized firms - unlike monopoly, a monopolistically competitive market has many firms
Firms are "price makers" - each of these firms have a degree of market power, so they are price makers
Low barriers to entry (i.e. means that firms can enter/leave easily) - like perfect competition, monopolistically competitive markets are easy to enter and leave
FirmsΒ break even in the long-run - as we'll see in more detail, in the long run, there is an adjustment in the market from which the market equilibrates to normal profits
Products sold areΒ differentiatedΒ - each firm will sell a related, but different product. For example, every fast food restaurant sells the same general type of product (food, but fast!) but may have different products specifically (I don't get tacos at Burger King)
Non-price competition is used - because firms are differentiated, they can use non-price competition, such as advertising, to signal substitutes to other businesses (them!) to consumers
Firms areΒ inefficient when left unregulated - like a monopoly, there will be deadweight loss both in the short run and long run because of...
Firms experience "excess capacity" in the long-run - these markets are productively inefficient! They do not produce where price = min ATC
As stated earlier, the market structure of monopolistic competition has characteristics that are like perfect competition, but also like monopolies. The chart below details which characteristics are similar to the other market structures.
Perfect Competition | Monopoly |
Many Firms | Market power / firms are "price makers" |
Low Barriers | Demand > MR |
Firms Compete | Non-price competition |
Firms break even in the long-run | Both allocatively and productively inefficient |
Monopolistic competition uses brand names and packaging as a type ofΒ non-price competition. The firms use this in order to stand out and be easily recognizable and distinguishable from their competitors. Think about Chick-fil-A; they are known for their customer service, making them different from other fast-food restaurants.
Another example is Nike's signature swoosh logo, which can be recognized all around the world. Nike also usesΒ product attributes and services as non-price competition. This helps them distinguish how their products are different from the others in the market. They may show how their shoes' soles provide consumers with more speed than other brands, thus enticing consumers to purchase their product.
The final method used for non-price competition isΒ advertising. Monopolistically competitive firms use advertising to generate demand for their product and to make consumer demand more elastic, meaning consumers will become more willing to switch from one product to another.
Monopolistic competitors can earn positive, negative, or zero economic profit in the short run, and they will break even in the long run (i.e. earn a normal profit) because of low barriers to entry/exit. The graph for a monopolistically competitive firm is very similar to a monopoly, and many people think they look almost identical. The main difference in the elasticity of the demand curve. The demand curve is more elastic in monopolistic competition than it is in a monopoly mainly because there are many more firms in monopolistic competition. However, in essence, a short run monopolistically competitive firm will look the same (in theory) to a monopoly.
You can see in the graph below that both the demand (D) and marginal revenue (MR) curves are more elastic. We still identify profit-maximizing output and price the same way in monopolistic competition as we do in a monopoly. We identify output where MR=MC, and then go up to the demand curve and over to find the price. This graph is missing ATC, but that could be drawn anywhere as long as it follows the traditional shape of the ATC curve and hits a minimum where ATC = MC.
When monopolistic firms earn a loss in the short run, itΒ compels firms to exit which provides less close substitutes and more market share for the existing firms. This leads to the demand and MR curves shifting right together so that the demand curve becomes tangent with ATC.
Excess capacityΒ is the difference between a firm's current inefficient level of production and the productively efficient level of output. In the long run, a perfectly competitive market is both allocatively inefficient (P != MC) and productively inefficient (P != min ATC). When we are productively efficient, we have no excess capacity.
<< Hide Menu
5 min readβ’june 18, 2024
Jeanne Stansak
dylan_black_2025
Jeanne Stansak
dylan_black_2025
Monopolistic competition is an imperfect market structure where many, various sized firms compete for market demand shares. This type of market structure has some characteristics that are the same or similar to perfect competition, as well as some characteristics that are the same or similar to monopolies. Some examples of monopolistic competition include fast-food restaurants, clothing companies, jewelers, hair salons, and furniture stores.
Many, various sized firms - unlike monopoly, a monopolistically competitive market has many firms
Firms are "price makers" - each of these firms have a degree of market power, so they are price makers
Low barriers to entry (i.e. means that firms can enter/leave easily) - like perfect competition, monopolistically competitive markets are easy to enter and leave
FirmsΒ break even in the long-run - as we'll see in more detail, in the long run, there is an adjustment in the market from which the market equilibrates to normal profits
Products sold areΒ differentiatedΒ - each firm will sell a related, but different product. For example, every fast food restaurant sells the same general type of product (food, but fast!) but may have different products specifically (I don't get tacos at Burger King)
Non-price competition is used - because firms are differentiated, they can use non-price competition, such as advertising, to signal substitutes to other businesses (them!) to consumers
Firms areΒ inefficient when left unregulated - like a monopoly, there will be deadweight loss both in the short run and long run because of...
Firms experience "excess capacity" in the long-run - these markets are productively inefficient! They do not produce where price = min ATC
As stated earlier, the market structure of monopolistic competition has characteristics that are like perfect competition, but also like monopolies. The chart below details which characteristics are similar to the other market structures.
Perfect Competition | Monopoly |
Many Firms | Market power / firms are "price makers" |
Low Barriers | Demand > MR |
Firms Compete | Non-price competition |
Firms break even in the long-run | Both allocatively and productively inefficient |
Monopolistic competition uses brand names and packaging as a type ofΒ non-price competition. The firms use this in order to stand out and be easily recognizable and distinguishable from their competitors. Think about Chick-fil-A; they are known for their customer service, making them different from other fast-food restaurants.
Another example is Nike's signature swoosh logo, which can be recognized all around the world. Nike also usesΒ product attributes and services as non-price competition. This helps them distinguish how their products are different from the others in the market. They may show how their shoes' soles provide consumers with more speed than other brands, thus enticing consumers to purchase their product.
The final method used for non-price competition isΒ advertising. Monopolistically competitive firms use advertising to generate demand for their product and to make consumer demand more elastic, meaning consumers will become more willing to switch from one product to another.
Monopolistic competitors can earn positive, negative, or zero economic profit in the short run, and they will break even in the long run (i.e. earn a normal profit) because of low barriers to entry/exit. The graph for a monopolistically competitive firm is very similar to a monopoly, and many people think they look almost identical. The main difference in the elasticity of the demand curve. The demand curve is more elastic in monopolistic competition than it is in a monopoly mainly because there are many more firms in monopolistic competition. However, in essence, a short run monopolistically competitive firm will look the same (in theory) to a monopoly.
You can see in the graph below that both the demand (D) and marginal revenue (MR) curves are more elastic. We still identify profit-maximizing output and price the same way in monopolistic competition as we do in a monopoly. We identify output where MR=MC, and then go up to the demand curve and over to find the price. This graph is missing ATC, but that could be drawn anywhere as long as it follows the traditional shape of the ATC curve and hits a minimum where ATC = MC.
When monopolistic firms earn a loss in the short run, itΒ compels firms to exit which provides less close substitutes and more market share for the existing firms. This leads to the demand and MR curves shifting right together so that the demand curve becomes tangent with ATC.
Excess capacityΒ is the difference between a firm's current inefficient level of production and the productively efficient level of output. In the long run, a perfectly competitive market is both allocatively inefficient (P != MC) and productively inefficient (P != min ATC). When we are productively efficient, we have no excess capacity.
Β© 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.